Europaudvalget 2007-08 (2. samling)
EUU Alm.del Bilag 74
Offentligt
517103_0001.png
Oxfam International Concerns With Initialled ‘Interim EPA’ Texts
Friday, 07 December 2007
Summary
Over the past two weeks, a number of “Interim
Economic Partnership Agreements”
(Interim EPA)
have been initialled between the European Commission (EC) and a number of African, Caribbean
1
and Pacific (ACP) countries . Such agreements were initiated by the EC in an effort to provide a
legal framework for the continuation of European trade preferences for ACP exports despite the
expiry, at the end of 2007, of the WTO Waiver in favour of the EU-ACP Cotonou Partnership
Agreement (CPA).
As the end of year deadline for negotiations has drawn nearer the EC has continued to ignore
both suggestions for alternatives and calls for more negotiating time, and instead threatened to
st
raise tariffs on January 1 2008 on exports from any ACP country that has not initialled an Interim
EPA. This has placed unacceptable pressure on ACP negotiators and governments. As a result,
many ACP countries, particularly those with larger trade with the EU, have been forced to lower
their expectations regarding what EPAs could deliver and have been pressed to secure any
agreement that will provide continued market access.
This has meant that many of the interim
agreements concluded were negotiated in a hurry and only a handful of their provisions
were actually negotiated.
The coverage of these agreements is very wide and disciplines are more stringent than required
under WTO rules. The structure and several of the conditions of these agreements actually
undermine the original objectives of EPAs and, in this sense, empty EPAs of their developmental
promise.
While the EC has portrayed the interim agreements as soft, not very binding and
flexible agreements, the provisions detailed in these agreements create a large number of
binding obligations for ACP governments and require a number of reforms. The
implementation of reforms or disciplines is often tied to specific deadlines and non
compliance with the terms of the agreements could be sanctioned through a dispute
settlement mechanism.
ACP countries are committing to liberalise up to 97% of imports from Europe, with almost all
liberalisation occurring within 10 to 15 years, and are freezing tariffs from the first day of
implementation. The safeguards fail to provide adequate protection for agriculture and fragile
industries. Trade policy space is virtually eliminated. In addition, ACP countries are obliged to
negotiate on areas such as services and investment, and prohibited from giving more preferential
treatment to third countries such as China or Brazil. Whilst ACP countries are required to make
such high levels of concessions, Europe makes no binding commitments on critical issues such
as improving rules of origin, addressing its subsidies, or increasing development assistance.
Oxfam International calls on European Governments to act urgently and:
Refrain from further putting pressure on ACP countries to initial agreements
Put in measures to ensure no ACP country will be left worse off if an agreement is not
initialled by the end of December 2007. This can be done by either allowing all ACP
countries to benefit from the regulation, or provisionally providing GSP+ to all non-LDCs
ACP countries, as Nigeria has requested.
Agree to renegotiate key elements of those agreements that have been initialled, in view
of the haste in which they were concluded
1
At the time of analysis , agreements of that type have been signed with all five countries of the East
African Community (EAC), Zimbabwe, Seychelles, Lesotho, Swaziland, Botswana, Mauritius, Papua New
Guinea, and Fiji
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
517103_0002.png
Areas Of Critical Concern For Development
Outlined below are the areas that Oxfam International regards as of deepest concern for
development. We recommend these provisions are renegotiated as a matter of urgency:
1. Scope and Pace Of ACP Market Opening
The EC agreed in principle to accept offers of tariff liberalisation from ACP countries of 80% over
25 years. However, in these Interim agreements, tariff elimination starts from the entry into force
of the agreement (2008) and the elimination of other barriers (export taxes) is not always gradual,
and may have to be implemented as early as 2008. Moreover, only a marginal share of trade
volume is subject to long implementation periods for tariff elimination. Even for least developed
countries the pace of liberalization is very fast.
For example:
§
In the SADC EPA 86% of Botswana, Lesotho and Swaziland’s liberalisation will take
place over two years; only 3 tariff lines are given a 10 year transition period; no products
are allowed periods of anything approaching 25 years.
For Mozambique, an LDC, there will be liberalisation of 80.5%, most of which is also to
take place upon immediate entry into force of the agreement (currently only 12% of
Mozambique’s trade is at zero percent).
In the EAC (East African Community, which includes four LDCs) EPA, 82% of the EU
imports will be liberalised. Of this, 62% will be liberalised after 2 years (51% of this is
currently at zero percent), and 80% after 15 years; only a final 2% of trade is liberalised
over a period of more than 15 years.
§
§
The EC has insisted on the inclusion of a
standstill clause
(e.g. Article 23 of the SADC EPA,
Article 13 of EAC EPA, Article 14 of the PNG EPA), which is not required by WTO rules.
In the SADC and PNG texts, the clause requires all tariffs to be frozen on products
subject to liberalization, whether this liberalization is due to happen immediately, or after
20 years. This prevents countries from using tariff flexibilities allowed by their
liberalisation commitments.
In the case of the EAC and ESA texts, it is even stricter as it freezes tariffs on all trade
between the parties,
whether or not these products are subject to liberalization.
As a
result, even if a product is on the ‘exclusion list’, the tariff on this product cannot be raised
after the entry into force of the agreement.
The EC has insisted on the removal of
export taxes.
Export taxes have been used for raising
revenue for developing countries across the world, accounting for more than 20% of government
2
revenue in Burundi, Sri Lanka, Mexico, Ethiopia and Guinea. The Interim EPAs require the
elimination of export taxes (PNG) or forbid the introduction of new taxes (EAC, SADC), with some
limited carve outs.
In the SADC text no new export taxes are to be introduced, and those existing will not be
increased (Article 24) except for specific circumstances and after ‘consultation with the
EC Party’
The EU is insisting on eliminating these in the context of the Doha round but developing countries
have not agreed. The EC’s insistence on the inclusion of a clause in EPAs is a red line for
Namibia, and one of the principle reasons for their non-initialling of the SADC EPA.
2
http://www.southcentre.org/info/Analysis/ExportTaxesAndRestrictions.pdf
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
517103_0003.png
Despite previous statements from the EC suggesting that
EU export subsidies
would be
eliminated for those products opened by the ACP, there is no clause in either the EAC or the
SADC EPA to this effect. Moreover, there are provisions that explicitly allow the EU to continue to
subsidise its own products. Article 36.4 in SADC, Article 17.4 in the EAC, and Article 23.4 in the
Pacific EPA are complete ‘carve out’ clauses from the EU’s national treatment obligation with
regard to domestic subsidies. The clause allows EU goods to be subsidised in the EU domestic
market which not only operates as a market barrier to ACP goods exported to the EU market, but
is also likely lead to a surplus of domestically subsidised products that are exported cheaply to
the ACP. These factors mean that the ACP countries will face unfair competition – both in the EU
market and in their own domestic markets.
The late inclusion by the EC of a
Most Favoured Nation
clause (for example, Article 28 in the
SADC EPA, Article 15 in EAC EPA) is a clear offensive interest and severely undermines the
scope for the ACP to make their own decisions about their market opening. This clause locks the
ACP into giving the same treatment to the EU that they give to any other major trading partner
such as the US, Japan, Brazil or China. This may be relevant to the Pacific ACP countries for
example, because their EPA signing will trigger negotiations on PACER, the Pacific Agreement
on Closer Economic Relations with Australia and New Zealand. ACP governments have strongly
objected to this clause and there is no requirement in the WTO or Cotonou to include it.
Even though agreements were reached in haste, under tremendous pressure, and in many cases
before impact assessments were completed, most Interim EPA texts do not include any provision
for reviewing tariff liberalisation commitments. Of the texts analysed, only one (PNG) incorporates
a clause for
‘modification of tariff commitments’
in the ‘event of serious difficulties’ (Article 13).
2. Inadequate safeguard clauses for ACP countries
In the absence of tariffs, effective safeguards are the main policy instrument that can be used to
protect the agricultural sector and existing industries from import surges, ensure food security,
and nurture the development of new ‘infant’ industries. As currently structured, the safeguards will
not provide adequate protection for ACP producers.
Texts on
bilateral safeguards
do not differ significantly from those currently available at WTO
which have proved inadequate for developing countries and difficult for them to implement. They
do not contain the flexibilities that the ACP and other developing countries have been calling for
in the WTO, in the form of a Special Safeguard Mechanism (SSM). The Caribbean countries have
proposed an automatic safeguard similar to the SSM in the EPA, but the EC has not accepted its
inclusion.
The safeguard clauses in the EAC, ESA and SADC EPA are limited by a number of
onerous procedures that have impeded their effective use in the context of other trade
agreements. In addition, safeguards are of limited duration and any safeguards
exceeding one year 'shall contain clear elements progressively leading to their
elimination at the end of the set period, at the latest.'
The Interim EPAs specifically provide for the use of
multilateral (WTO) safeguards
including the
Special Agricultural Safeguard under Article 5 of the WTO Agreement on Agriculture.
In some texts the EC has agreed to exempt initially ACP exports from imposition of
multilateral safeguards (SADC, EAC) but
only for the first five years.
In other texts even
such limited exemption is at the EC’s discretion (Papua New Guinea).
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
517103_0004.png
The articles that include so-called
‘infant industry clauses’
are extremely deceptive in that they
are, in reality, no more than ordinary safeguards by a different name. The so-called ‘infant
industry safeguard clauses’ are heavily restricted and limited to mitigating the damage of import
surges for existing sectors – not for building up new sectors. Moreover, these normal safeguards
are also difficult to use, based upon ACP experience in other trade arrangements.
The initial duration for which these clauses can be used is only 2 years in most initialled
texts, although it is up to 7 years for Papua New Guinea and 12 years for LDCs in the
Pacific region. Given the length of time it takes an industry to develop, there is no utility in
a clause only lasting for 2 years.
The use of these special safeguards is prohibited after 10 years (East African
Community), 12 years (Botswana, Swaziland and Lesotho), 15 years (Mozambique) and
in others after 20 years (Papua New Guinea). Given that the industrialisation process
takes generations, to enable progressive development of industries, there should be no
sunset clause for the use of this critical development tool.
For such clauses to reflect their title they should be based on the old clause in Part IV of
the EEC Treaty and the Yaoundé Conventions, which allowed an ACP country to ‘retain
or introduce customs duties … which correspond to its development needs or its
industrialization requirements or which are intended to contribute to its budget’
Despite major problems of
food security
across the ACP, most EPA texts do not even note that
trade liberalization can heighten food insecurity. The PNG EPA text is an exception, in that it
acknowledges that the removal of tariffs can ‘pose significant challenges’ to food security.
However the text is very weak as the proposed solution is ‘consultation’ between the parties and
the possible use of bilateral safeguards as the only remedial measure (PNG Article 46).
3. Scope and Coverage Of EU Market Opening
The commercial gains arising from the Duty Free Quota Free offer itself are limited because of
the failure of the EU to substantially improve rules or origin, the retention of transition periods on
two key products (sugar and rice) and strict safeguards that limit ACP access to EU markets.
The latest EU offer on
Rules Of Origin
(Regulation COM (2007) 717 final, November 13 2007),
which will be applied until a ‘Full EPA’ comes into force, contains only minor improvements to
existing rules but even these are still disputed by several EU Member States.
However,
cumulation is restricted to those ACP countries that have signed an EPA, potentially destroying
production processes that span ACP countries that have not signed.
Significant improvements are made for textiles and clothing (Product level RoO) but
these are partly undermined by provisions on value tolerance (Article 4) which are
stricter
than under Cotonou.
The requirements for fish (Product level RoO) remain largely unchanged and continue to
form a significant barrier. There are some minor improvements only applicable to the
export of fish from the Pacific but in order to benefit, countries are subject to a range of
administrative and reporting requirements (Article 4)
No industrial products other than textiles and clothing have seen any change
Unlike Cotonou, the only ACP countries that will benefit from cumulation are those that
have concluded a free trade agreement (Article 2 of Title II), potentially destroying
exports that rely on inputs from ACP countries that have not initialed Interim EPAs.
Such an approach could also undermine capacities to add value between countries that
are party to and those not party to an EPA, since no cumulation is allowed on rules of
origin for exports under different EU preferential regimes
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
517103_0005.png
In the Interim EPAs, there is general language (e.g. EAC Article 12, PNG Article 8) about the
need to review these rules of origin. But in terms of actual commitments, the EU is only
committing to consider the possibility of offering more ‘development-friendly’ RoOs in the future.
This is unfair on several counts: without binding agreement on RoOs, it is very difficult for the
ACP to assess the worth of the EU’s market access offer. In addition, as the permanent RoOs are
to be negotiated in the future, after the main bulk of EPA terms have been agreed, the ACP will
have much less scope to influence them.
The EU can use bilateral safeguards against ACP imports more readily than it could under
Cotonou, undermining the benefits of additional market access.
The EU regulation (Regulation COM (2007) 717 final, November 13 2007) which will
st
apply from January 1 2008 no longer requires ‘serious disturbance’ but only
‘disturbance’ (Article 12). This is a lesser standard than in the EC’s other trade
agreements (including Cotonou and GSP) and stricter than under the WTO safeguards
Agreement.
Moreover many of the provisions of the Cotonou Agreement requiring the EC, in the
provision of safeguards, to limit damage to ACP countries are now missing.
Safeguards on sugar over a set quantity are stricter than they were under the Sugar
Protocol
4. Services and Investment
Many ACP countries have insisted that they do not want to include commitments on trade related
areas. However, the EC has insisted on including commitments go beyond a ‘commitment to
negotiate’ on services and investment as they are significant agreement of ACP countries to
liberalise
these sectors even before the terms of this liberalisation have been negotiated.
In the SADC EPA there are commitments to conclude negotiations in these areas (under
Article 67), even though they are not required for WTO compatibility and are in clear
contravention of SADC’s collective position
In SADC signatories have been committed to ‘complete’ negotiations on services no later
than 31 December 2008, including a
liberalisation schedule for one service sector for
each participating SADC EPA State; commitment to a standstill as specified in Article
V.1.b(ii) GATS, for all services sectors; agreement to negotiate progressive liberalisation
with substantial sectoral coverage within a period of three years following the conclusion
of the full EPA.”
SADC signatories also commit to
negotiate an Investment chapter, taking account the
relevant provisions of the SADC Protocol on Finance and Investment, no later than 31
December 2008.
Other countries or regions that have stressed they did not want to commit to negotiate in
these areas have still had to sign up to a commitment to continue negotiating (e.g. EAC
Chapter V commits parties to negotiate and links this in same chapter as Economic and
Development cooperation)
5. Regional Integration
Precisely because interim agreements will, de facto, be applied in several ACP countries who
have not made a decision to sign them, these agreements will have an inevitable detrimental
impact on the regional economic integration, particularly in Africa. SACU, the oldest customs
union in the world, is currently divided with 3 countries having initialled an interim agreement with
the EC, one country refusing to do so (Namibia), and another one (South Africa) applying a
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
separate trade agreement with the EU. SADC, where a detailed plan for a common market had
been established, is also severely divided. This is a blatant contradiction with some of the most
prominent objectives of EPAs, and one which was thought to deliver greatest development
potential: that of building upon and reinforcing regional integration.
This approach has a number of serious consequences, all of them extremely counter-productive
for regional integration.
§
ACP countries are now submitting separate and un-harmonised tariff liberalisation
schedules, not agreed as a region, which will commit them to liberalising to the EU before
they have decided what to liberalise to each other (in the case of COMESA for example).
§
Since revision clauses are absent or inadequate in these EPA texts, the separate EPAs
or trade regimes within a region would prevent the further integration of the region to a
customs union.
§
In addition to this, countries not signed up will have to impose stricter border controls to
guard against EU goods entering their markets through neighbouring countries, leading
to defensiveness between regional neighbours and greater barriers to regional trade
§
In order to avoid this fragmentation, the only option for countries left behind by regional
neighbours that have already signed an EPA, would be to join up to an agreement that
has been designed by the stronger partners without their interests in mind. This would in
turn leave these weaker countries unable to protect their own sensitive sectors, in cases
where these differ from those of their more advanced neighbours
6. Commitments on development
The conclusion of interim agreements does not signify that there is a convergence of views
among the ACP countries and the EU as to the instruments through which EPAs will deliver
development. Several areas of interest to ACP governments are not included in the interim
agreements. It is likely that, having agreed to liberalise trade in goods, ACP governments have
little negotiating leverage to engage in a good faith discussion with the EC on topics of their
interest. This will further accentuate the gap in political, economic and negotiating capacity that
divides ACP and EC negotiators.
In this sense, it is unfortunate that development cooperation provisions, both financial and non-
financial, are barely developed and often absent from the EPA. No binding link is made between
the implementation of trade reforms and financial assistance from the EU. The details of
development cooperation instruments (e.g. Regional EPA Funds) remain to be negotiated at a
later stage. Other instruments cited (e.g. EDF) are not linked in a binding manner to the interim
agreements. In fact, development assistance is explicitly excluded from the remit of the interim
EPA dispute settlement mechanism.
7. Dispute Settlement, Monitoring, Evaluation and Review Mechanism
The detailed obligations contained in the interim agreements are subject to enforcement through
a detailed dispute settlement mechanism. This reflects the European Commission’s view that the
agreements will only deliver development if they are entirely implemented and applied, which
translates in a focus on enforcement. This contrasts with the ACP view that application and
enforcement are also linked to administrative capacity, which relates to technical and financial
assistance to support the implementation of reforms.
Moreover, a focus on strict enforcement can fail to deliver development benefits (e.g. poverty
reduction) if not accompanied by a mechanism to monitor and evaluate the impacts of the
agreement. The agreements concluded either have no provision for an evaluation of the
agreement and possible review, or have only weak language in that regard.
ENDS